International Organization http://journals.cambridge.orq/INO Additional services for International Organization: Email alerts:Click here Subscriptions:Click here Commercial reprints:Click here Terms of use:Click here The Emperor Has No Clothes:The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market Jeff D.Colgan International Organization/Volume 68 Issue 03 June 2014,pp 599-632 DOl:10.1017/S0020818313000489.Published online:06 June 2014 Link to this article:http://iournals cambridge org/abstract S0020818313000489 How to cite this article: Jeff D.Colgan(2014).The Emperor Has No Clothes:The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market.International Organization,68,pp 599-632 doi:10.1017/ S0020818313000489 Request Permissions Click here CAMNE JOURNALS Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/INO,IP address:211.80.95.69 on 14 Jan 2015
International Organization http://journals.cambridge.org/INO Additional services for International Organization: Email alerts: Click here Subscriptions: Click here Commercial reprints: Click here Terms of use : Click here The Emperor Has No Clothes: The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market Jeff D. Colgan International Organization / Volume 68 / Issue 03 / June 2014, pp 599 - 632 DOI: 10.1017/S0020818313000489, Published online: 06 June 2014 Link to this article: http://journals.cambridge.org/abstract_S0020818313000489 How to cite this article: Jeff D. Colgan (2014). The Emperor Has No Clothes: The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market. International Organization, 68, pp 599-632 doi:10.1017/ S0020818313000489 Request Permissions : Click here Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/INO, IP address: 211.80.95.69 on 14 Jan 2015
The Emperor Has No Clothes:The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market Jeff D.Colgan Abstract Scholars have long debated the causal impact of international institutions such as the World Trade Organization or the International Monetary Fund.This study investigates Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC),an organization that purports to have significant influence over the market for the world's most important commodity-petroleum.Using four empirical tests,I find that OPEC has little or no impact on its members'production levels.These findings prompt the question of why so many people,including scholars,believe in OPEC's influence over the world's oil supply.The idea of OPEC as a cartel is a"rational myth"that supports the organization's true principal function,which is to generate political benefits for its members.One benefit it generates is international prestige.I test this idea using data on diplomatic rep- resentation and find that OPEC membership is associated with increased international recognition by other states.Overall,these findings help one to better understand inter- national regimes and the process of ideational change in world politics. Scholars have long debated the causal impact of international institutions.Existing research considers the impact of the World Trade Organization(WTO)on trade,the International Monetary Fund (IMF)on fiscal and monetary policies,2 and human rights treaties on state behavior.3 Notable mostly for its absence within political science is the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries(OPEC),an institution that many people believe can and does manipulate the global price of oil.This is surprising.Oil is the world's most important commodity,4 and changes in its price are commonly believed to have powerful economic and political consequences. Moreover,OPEC represents an intriguing test case for theories of international cooperation.Like the WTO but unlike human rights treaties,there is a direct material I thank Michael Aklin,Andre Bernier,David Bosco,Sarah Bush,Ashley Connor,Sikina Jinnah,Robert Keohane,Kristina Johnson,Moonhawk Kim,James Morrison,Margaret Peters,Margaret Roberts,David Steinberg,Jordan Tama,Felicity Vabulas,Sharon Weiner,and participants at the Princeton University Conference on Environmental Politics,the EPSA 2012 meeting,and the University of Wisconsin- Madison Interational Relations Colloguium,for helpful feedback on early versions of this article. Special thanks to David Parker and Laina Stuebner for research assistance.Any remaining errors are my own.I gratefully acknowledge support from American University and the Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. 1.See Rose 2004 and 2007;and Goldstein,Rivers,and Tomz 2007. 2.See Simmons and Hopkins 2005;and von Stein 2005. 3.See Sikkink 2011:and Hafner-Burton and Ron 2009. 4.By "most important commodity market,"I mean oil is the most valuable commodity traded inter- nationally.measured by total market. International Organization 68.Summer 2014,pp.599-632 The IO Foundation,2014 doi:10.1017/S0020818313000489
The Emperor Has No Clothes: The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market Jeff D. Colgan Abstract Scholars have long debated the causal impact of international institutions such as the World Trade Organization or the International Monetary Fund. This study investigates Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), an organization that purports to have significant influence over the market for the world’s most important commodity–petroleum. Using four empirical tests, I find that OPEC has little or no impact on its members’ production levels. These findings prompt the question of why so many people, including scholars, believe in OPEC’s influence over the world’s oil supply. The idea of OPEC as a cartel is a “rational myth” that supports the organization’s true principal function, which is to generate political benefits for its members. One benefit it generates is international prestige. I test this idea using data on diplomatic representation and find that OPEC membership is associated with increased international recognition by other states. Overall, these findings help one to better understand international regimes and the process of ideational change in world politics. Scholars have long debated the causal impact of international institutions. Existing research considers the impact of the World Trade Organization (WTO) on trade,1 the International Monetary Fund (IMF) on fiscal and monetary policies,2 and human rights treaties on state behavior.3 Notable mostly for its absence within political science is the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), an institution that many people believe can and does manipulate the global price of oil. This is surprising. Oil is the world’s most important commodity,4 and changes in its price are commonly believed to have powerful economic and political consequences. Moreover, OPEC represents an intriguing test case for theories of international cooperation. Like the WTO but unlike human rights treaties, there is a direct material I thank Michael Aklin, André Bernier, David Bosco, Sarah Bush, Ashley Connor, Sikina Jinnah, Robert Keohane, Kristina Johnson, Moonhawk Kim, James Morrison, Margaret Peters, Margaret Roberts, David Steinberg, Jordan Tama, Felicity Vabulas, Sharon Weiner, and participants at the Princeton University Conference on Environmental Politics, the EPSA 2012 meeting, and the University of WisconsinMadison International Relations Colloquium, for helpful feedback on early versions of this article. Special thanks to David Parker and Laina Stuebner for research assistance. Any remaining errors are my own. I gratefully acknowledge support from American University and the Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. 1. See Rose 2004 and 2007; and Goldstein, Rivers, and Tomz 2007. 2. See Simmons and Hopkins 2005; and von Stein 2005. 3. See Sikkink 2011; and Hafner-Burton and Ron 2009. 4. By “most important commodity market,” I mean oil is the most valuable commodity traded internationally, measured by total market. International Organization 68, Summer 2014, pp. 599–632 © The IO Foundation, 2014 doi:10.1017/S0020818313000489
600 International Organization reward for collective action in OPEC's case,so one might expect deep cooperation. Popular wisdom also holds that OPEC is influential,but economic studies investi- gating OPEC's market impact have had difficulty finding conclusive evidence. This generates two questions.First,does OPEC operate as a cartel,meaning that it significantly restricts its members'oil production in order to affect prices?Second, if OPEC is not actually a cartel,why do so many people believe that it is? The first step is to investigate whether OPEC actually acts as a cartel.5 Using some of the same tests that in the past have helped evaluate the impact of the WTO and other organizations,I find that OPEC rarely if ever constrains or influences the oil production rate of its member states.Although this article is not the first to question OPEC's effec- tiveness in restricting the oil supply,6 there is sufficient debate and ambiguity in the existing literature to sustain OPEC's image,even among scholars,as a cartel that manipulates the price of oil by restricting supply.Therefore,I conduct four empirical tests in search of OPEC's effect on oil production,at least two of which are entirely novel.I find that OPEC membership is not significantly correlated with lower oil pro- duction once other relevant factors are controlled for.At a minimum,there is no good evidence to believe that OPEC is a cartel,and I shift the burden of proof to those who would claim that OPEC facilitates economic collusion.I make no claim about whether OPEC could restrict oil supply in principle;I simply argue that it does not do so in prac- tice.This is due in part,but not principally,to endemic cheating by OPEC members (that is,oil production in excess of their quotas).A cartel needs to set tough goals and meet them;OPEC sets easy goals and fails to meet even those. There was one occasion on which OPEC did have a significant impact on the world oil market,namely the 1973 oil crisis,but OPEC's role in the crisis has been greatly misunderstood.That event helped to endow OPEC with a reputation as a manipulator of world oil markets. If OPEC does not operate as a cartel,why do so many people believe that it does? The idea of OPEC as a cartel is a"rational myth"that supports the organization's true principal function,which is to generate political benefits for its members.Scholars have found that various organizations adopt rational myths,?and OPEC would not be the first international institution to outlive its original mandate.8 OPEC's current role is obscured in part by the complexity of the world oil market,in part by the fact that one of its members,Saudi Arabia,probably does have some market power on its own (distinct from the organization to which it belongs),and in part by misdirection by OPEC itself.OPEC's perceived market power is a useful fiction that generates pol- itical benefits for its members with domestic and interational audiences. 5.A cartel is defined as a group of firms(or states,in this case)that creates agreements about quantities to produce or prices to charge.Mankiw 2011,351.More details later. 6.As I show,the debate thus far has been principally among economists;the paucity of attention given to OPEC noted earlier describes political science.This disciplinary divergence has consequences:economic analyses of OPEC typically omit important political variables,potentially biasing the results. 7.See McNamara 2002;Boiral 2007;and Meyer and Rowan 1977. 8.See Bamett and Finnemore 1999:Gray 2011:Duffield 1994:and Wallander 2000
reward for collective action in OPEC’s case, so one might expect deep cooperation. Popular wisdom also holds that OPEC is influential, but economic studies investigating OPEC’s market impact have had difficulty finding conclusive evidence. This generates two questions. First, does OPEC operate as a cartel, meaning that it significantly restricts its members’ oil production in order to affect prices? Second, if OPEC is not actually a cartel, why do so many people believe that it is? The first step is to investigate whether OPEC actually acts as a cartel.5 Using some of the same tests that in the past have helped evaluate the impact of the WTO and other organizations, I find that OPEC rarely if ever constrains or influences the oil production rate of its member states. Although this article is not the first to question OPEC’s effectiveness in restricting the oil supply,6 there is sufficient debate and ambiguity in the existing literature to sustain OPEC’s image, even among scholars, as a cartel that manipulates the price of oil by restricting supply. Therefore, I conduct four empirical tests in search of OPEC’s effect on oil production, at least two of which are entirely novel. I find that OPEC membership is not significantly correlated with lower oil production once other relevant factors are controlled for. At a minimum, there is no good evidence to believe that OPEC is a cartel, and I shift the burden of proof to those who would claim that OPEC facilitates economic collusion. I make no claim about whether OPEC could restrict oil supply in principle; I simply argue that it does not do so in practice. This is due in part, but not principally, to endemic cheating by OPEC members (that is, oil production in excess of their quotas). A cartel needs to set tough goals and meet them; OPEC sets easy goals and fails to meet even those. There was one occasion on which OPEC did have a significant impact on the world oil market, namely the 1973 oil crisis, but OPEC’s role in the crisis has been greatly misunderstood. That event helped to endow OPEC with a reputation as a manipulator of world oil markets. If OPEC does not operate as a cartel, why do so many people believe that it does? The idea of OPEC as a cartel is a “rational myth” that supports the organization’s true principal function, which is to generate political benefits for its members. Scholars have found that various organizations adopt rational myths,7 and OPEC would not be the first international institution to outlive its original mandate.8 OPEC’s current role is obscured in part by the complexity of the world oil market, in part by the fact that one of its members, Saudi Arabia, probably does have some market power on its own (distinct from the organization to which it belongs), and in part by misdirection by OPEC itself. OPEC’s perceived market power is a useful fiction that generates political benefits for its members with domestic and international audiences. 5. A cartel is defined as a group of firms (or states, in this case) that creates agreements about quantities to produce or prices to charge. Mankiw 2011, 351. More details later. 6. As I show, the debate thus far has been principally among economists; the paucity of attention given to OPEC noted earlier describes political science. This disciplinary divergence has consequences: economic analyses of OPEC typically omit important political variables, potentially biasing the results. 7. See McNamara 2002; Boiral 2007; and Meyer and Rowan 1977. 8. See Barnett and Finnemore 1999; Gray 2011; Duffield 1994; and Wallander 2000. 600 International Organization
The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market 601 I test this argument using a cross-national data set on diplomatic recognition,and show that OPEC membership is significantly correlated with increased ambassadorial representation from other countries.Consequently,policy-makers within OPEC have no incentive to undermine the idea that OPEC influences the world oil market.This does not necessarily mean that they are actively lying,but rather that they have an incentive to behave in ways that are consistent with the cartel idea so long as that be- havior is not too costly.Other knowledgeable actors outside of OPEC fail to dispel the myth for various reasons.In sum,the story of OPEC is mostly about politics, not economics. Beyond the intrinsic importance of OPEC and the world oil market,this inquiry offers three important lessons about international politics.First,the fact that such a widespread belief could be wrong sheds light on the process of ideational change and the failure to update beliefs.This contributes to a growing literature suggesting that actors'knowledge of causation,especially in economic affairs,is imperfect. Second,the case of OPEC offers a complement to understanding international organ- izations as a product of rational design.10 Most accounts assume that there is a good fit between an organization's original mandate and its enduring function,but OPEC's history suggests that at least some organizations are designed long before their event- ual function is fully understood.Third,the article fills a gap in the research assessing the impact of institutions,moving beyond the oft-studied WTO and IMF/World Bank.It contributes to recent work on oil-producing states'participation in inter- national organizations.12 Finally,the evidence that OPEC is not a cartel calls into question research in political science that is based on that premise.13 Existing Ideas About OPEC OPEC was established in 1960.Its founders,modeling it after the Texas Railroad Commission,hoped that it would act as a cartel.14 Initially this proved impossible because OPEC member countries did not gain control of their own oil production decisions until the 1970s.OPEC began to assign formal production quotas only in 1982.The organization meets regularly and makes decisions by consensus,which effectively gives each state a veto.15 OPEC currently has twelve member states: 9.See Darden 2009;Legro 2005;Blyth 2002;and MeNamara 2002. 10.Koremenos,Lipson,and Snidal 2001. 11.See Martin and Simmons 1998;and Botcheva and Martin 2001. 12.See Lesage,Van de Graaf,and Westphal 2010:Ross and Voeten 2011;Rudra and Jensen 2011; Goldthau and Witte 2011;Colgan,Keohane,and Van de Graaf 2012;and Baccini,Lenzi,and Thurer 2013. 13.See Blaydes 2004;and Alt,Calvert,and Humes 1988. 14.See Parra 2004;and Yergin 2008. 15.OPEC can set or change its members'quotas for oil production at any of its regular meetings,or it can do so in an"extraordinary session."Each member state appoints a delegate to represent it at OPEC meet- ings,typically the Minister of Oil or its equivalent
I test this argument using a cross-national data set on diplomatic recognition, and show that OPEC membership is significantly correlated with increased ambassadorial representation from other countries. Consequently, policy-makers within OPEC have no incentive to undermine the idea that OPEC influences the world oil market. This does not necessarily mean that they are actively lying, but rather that they have an incentive to behave in ways that are consistent with the cartel idea so long as that behavior is not too costly. Other knowledgeable actors outside of OPEC fail to dispel the myth for various reasons. In sum, the story of OPEC is mostly about politics, not economics. Beyond the intrinsic importance of OPEC and the world oil market, this inquiry offers three important lessons about international politics. First, the fact that such a widespread belief could be wrong sheds light on the process of ideational change and the failure to update beliefs. This contributes to a growing literature suggesting that actors’ knowledge of causation, especially in economic affairs, is imperfect.9 Second, the case of OPEC offers a complement to understanding international organizations as a product of rational design.10 Most accounts assume that there is a good fit between an organization’s original mandate and its enduring function, but OPEC’s history suggests that at least some organizations are designed long before their eventual function is fully understood. Third, the article fills a gap in the research assessing the impact of institutions,11 moving beyond the oft-studied WTO and IMF/World Bank. It contributes to recent work on oil-producing states’ participation in international organizations.12 Finally, the evidence that OPEC is not a cartel calls into question research in political science that is based on that premise.13 Existing Ideas About OPEC OPEC was established in 1960. Its founders, modeling it after the Texas Railroad Commission, hoped that it would act as a cartel.14 Initially this proved impossible because OPEC member countries did not gain control of their own oil production decisions until the 1970s. OPEC began to assign formal production quotas only in 1982. The organization meets regularly and makes decisions by consensus, which effectively gives each state a veto.15 OPEC currently has twelve member states: 9. See Darden 2009; Legro 2005; Blyth 2002; and McNamara 2002. 10. Koremenos, Lipson, and Snidal 2001. 11. See Martin and Simmons 1998; and Botcheva and Martin 2001. 12. See Lesage, Van de Graaf, and Westphal 2010; Ross and Voeten 2011; Rudra and Jensen 2011; Goldthau and Witte 2011; Colgan, Keohane, and Van de Graaf 2012; and Baccini, Lenzi, and Thurner 2013. 13. See Blaydes 2004; and Alt, Calvert, and Humes 1988. 14. See Parra 2004; and Yergin 2008. 15. OPEC can set or change its members’ quotas for oil production at any of its regular meetings, or it can do so in an “extraordinary session.” Each member state appoints a delegate to represent it at OPEC meetings, typically the Minister of Oil or its equivalent. The Limits of OPEC in the Global Oil Market 601
602 International Organization Algeria,Angola,Ecuador,Iran,Iraq.Kuwait,Libya,Nigeria,Qatar,Saudi Arabia, the UAE,and Venezuela.16 Collectively,OPEC produced 41 percent of the world total in 2009,though individually even its largest producer has a relatively small market share (Saudi Arabia has 12 percent).17 If OPEC were able to cooperate flawlessly,it might exert significant market influence. The significant oil price increases of the 1970s convinced many observers that OPEC had become the cartel that its founders envisioned.8 Krasner even argued in a 1974 article entitled "Oil Is the Exception"that the characteristics of oil made it especially susceptible to an international cartel compared with other commod- ities.19 Yet over time many studies have cast significant doubt on the idea that OPEC is a cartel.20 Some scholars suggested a "dominant producer"model, namely that Saudi Arabia alone exerted market power,because it seems to be the only state with sizeable surplus production capacity.21 Others simply argued that OPEC had little market impact and that oil prices were the product of other market factors.22 More recently,scholars have noted a series of limitations on OPEC's effec- tiveness.23 For instance,Bremond and others found that OPEC is a price taker,not a price setter,in the majority of subperiods that they consider.24 Still,none of the critics of the OPEC-as-cartel hypothesis offered a compelling alternative account of the organization's role.25 Even as scholars cast doubts on its effectiveness,there was sufficient ambiguity to sustain OPEC's image as a cartel.Kaufman and colleagues answer the question "Does OPEC matter?"(for oil prices and production)in the affirmative,as others do.26 Smith finds that "OPEC is much more than a noncooperative oligopoly,but less than a frictionless cartel(that is,multiplant monopoly)."27 Despite pointing to OPEC's limitations,Bremond and colleagues conclude that"OPEC influence has evolved through time"rather than rejecting it as a cartel,and they support the idea that a membership subset sustains OPEC's ability to influence markets,as earlier research argued.28 16.Indonesia and Gabon were previously members. 17.BP Statistical Review of World Energy. 18.See Osbome 1976:Seymour 1980;Doran 1980;and Adelman 1982.See also internal US government reactions during the 1970s in Qaimmaqami and Keefer 2011. 19.Krasner 1974. 20.See Griffin 1985;Dahl and Yuicel 1991;Alhajji and Huettner 2000;Barsky and Kilian 2004:Reynolds and Pippenger 2010:and Caims and Calfucura 2012. 21.Moran 1982.Adelman suggests that OPEC wobbles between acting as a dominant firm and as part of a cartel depending on market conditions.Adelman 1982 22.See Johany 1980;and MacAvoy 1982. 23.See Gulen 1996;Kohl 2002;Kaufman et al.2004 and 2008;Smith 2005;and Hyndman 2008. 24.Bremond,Hache,and Mignon 2012,125. 25.For an early suggestion about OPEC's myth making,see Doran,1977 (chap.6). 26.See Kaufman et al.2004 and 2008;Demirer and Kutan 2006;and Bentzen 2007. 27.Smith2005,74. 28.See Bremond,Hache,and Mignon 2012;Teece 1982;and Cremer and Salehi-Isfahani 1980
Algeria, Angola, Ecuador, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the UAE, and Venezuela.16 Collectively, OPEC produced 41 percent of the world total in 2009, though individually even its largest producer has a relatively small market share (Saudi Arabia has 12 percent).17 If OPEC were able to cooperate flawlessly, it might exert significant market influence. The significant oil price increases of the 1970s convinced many observers that OPEC had become the cartel that its founders envisioned.18 Krasner even argued in a 1974 article entitled “Oil Is the Exception” that the characteristics of oil made it especially susceptible to an international cartel compared with other commodities.19 Yet over time many studies have cast significant doubt on the idea that OPEC is a cartel.20 Some scholars suggested a “dominant producer” model, namely that Saudi Arabia alone exerted market power, because it seems to be the only state with sizeable surplus production capacity.21 Others simply argued that OPEC had little market impact and that oil prices were the product of other market factors.22 More recently, scholars have noted a series of limitations on OPEC’s effectiveness.23 For instance, Brémond and others found that OPEC is a price taker, not a price setter, in the majority of subperiods that they consider.24 Still, none of the critics of the OPEC-as-cartel hypothesis offered a compelling alternative account of the organization’s role.25 Even as scholars cast doubts on its effectiveness, there was sufficient ambiguity to sustain OPEC’s image as a cartel. Kaufman and colleagues answer the question “Does OPEC matter?” (for oil prices and production) in the affirmative, as others do.26 Smith finds that “OPEC is much more than a noncooperative oligopoly, but less than a frictionless cartel ( that is, multiplant monopoly).”27 Despite pointing to OPEC’s limitations, Brémond and colleagues conclude that “OPEC influence has evolved through time” rather than rejecting it as a cartel, and they support the idea that a membership subset sustains OPEC’s ability to influence markets, as earlier research argued.28 16. Indonesia and Gabon were previously members. 17. BP Statistical Review of World Energy. 18. See Osborne 1976; Seymour 1980; Doran 1980; and Adelman 1982. See also internal US government reactions during the 1970s in Qaimmaqami and Keefer 2011. 19. Krasner 1974. 20. See Griffin 1985; Dahl and Yücel 1991; Alhajji and Huettner 2000; Barsky and Kilian 2004; Reynolds and Pippenger 2010; and Cairns and Calfucura 2012. 21. Moran 1982. Adelman suggests that OPEC wobbles between acting as a dominant firm and as part of a cartel depending on market conditions. Adelman 1982. 22. See Johany 1980; and MacAvoy 1982. 23. See Gülen 1996; Kohl 2002; Kaufman et al. 2004 and 2008; Smith 2005; and Hyndman 2008. 24. Brémond, Hache, and Mignon 2012, 125. 25. For an early suggestion about OPEC’s myth making, see Doran, 1977 (chap. 6). 26. See Kaufman et al. 2004 and 2008; Demirer and Kutan 2006; and Bentzen 2007. 27. Smith 2005, 74. 28. See Brémond, Hache, and Mignon 2012; Teece 1982; and Crémer and Salehi-Isfahani 1980. 602 International Organization