THE BOTTOM BILLION Why the Poorest Countries are Failing and What Can Be Done About It PAUL COLLIER
Contents Preface ix Part 1 What's the Issue? 1.Falling Behind and Falling Apart: The Bottom Billion 3 Part 2 The Traps 2.The Conflict Trap 17 3.The Natural Resource Trap 38 4.Landlocked with Bad Neighbors 53 5.Bad Governance in a Small Country 64 Part 3 An Interlude:Globalization to the Rescue? 6.On Missing the Boat:The Marginalization of the Bottom Billion in the World Economy 79 Part 4 The Instruments 7.Aid to the Rescue?99 8.Military Intervention 124 9.Laws and Charters 135 10.Trade Policy for Reversing Marginalization 157
Contents Preface ix Part 1 What’s the Issue? 1. Falling Behind and Falling Apart: The Bottom Billion 3 Part 2 The Traps 2. The Conflict Trap 17 3. The Natural Resource Trap 38 4. Landlocked with Bad Neighbors 53 5. Bad Governance in a Small Country 64 Part 3 An Interlude: Globalization to the Rescue? 6. On Missing the Boat: The Marginalization of the Bottom Billion in the World Economy 79 Part 4 The Instruments 7. Aid to the Rescue? 99 8. Military Intervention 124 9. Laws and Charters 135 10. Trade Policy for Reversing Marginalization 157
viii CONTENTS Part 5 The Struggle for the Bottom Billion 11.An Agenda for Action 175 Research on Which This Book Is Based 193 Index 197
Part 5 The Struggle for the Bottom Billion 11. An Agenda for Action 175 Research on Which This Book Is Based 193 Index 197 viii CONTENTS
Preface I WAS A STUDENT at Oxford in 1968.I remember joining something called the Oxford Revolutionary Socialist Students,a name now beyond parody.But it all seemed simple then.When I graduated I wanted to put my knowledge of economics to use in Africa.Africa's new countries were ill-equipped,and scarcely any Africans had received the sort of education I had just been through.At the time many Oxford students had family con- nections with Africa,as their fathers had been colonial administrators.Not in my case-my father was a butcher in Yorkshire.But some of those colo- nial connections must have rubbed off on me:the father of my friend had been the governor general of a little country called Nyasaland,and so I read up on it.What I read made me resolve to go there.Renamed Malawi,it was the poorest country on the continent.It is easier to rename countries than to change them:thirty-five years later it is still as dirt poor as it was then.In an- other thirty-five years I doubt it will be much different,unless...This book is about that"unless." Malawi hasn't changed much in the last thirty-five years,and in one sense neither have I:I'm still working on Africa,now as a professor at Ox- ford.In between I've been a professor at Harvard,and directed the World Bank's research department,where I was brought in by Joe Stiglitz to strengthen its focus on the poorest countries.Indeed,my first assignment for the World Bank was to go with Joe to Ethiopia.Since I had just married, the trip was my honeymoon,but with Joe instead of my wife.Fortunately
Preface I was a student at Oxford in 1968. I remember joining something called the Oxford Revolutionary Socialist Students, a name now beyond parody. But it all seemed simple then. When I graduated I wanted to put my knowledge of economics to use in Africa. Africa’s new countries were ill-equipped, and scarcely any Africans had received the sort of education I had just been through. At the time many Oxford students had family connections with Africa, as their fathers had been colonial administrators. Not in my case—my father was a butcher in Yorkshire. But some of those colonial connections must have rubbed off on me: the father of my friend had been the governor general of a little country called Nyasaland, and so I read up on it. What I read made me resolve to go there. Renamed Malawi, it was the poorest country on the continent. It is easier to rename countries than to change them: thirty-five years later it is still as dirt poor as it was then. In another thirty-five years I doubt it will be much different, unless . . . This book is about that “unless.” Malawi hasn’t changed much in the last thirty-five years, and in one sense neither have I: I’m still working on Africa, now as a professor at Oxford. In between I’ve been a professor at Harvard, and directed the World Bank’s research department, where I was brought in by Joe Stiglitz to strengthen its focus on the poorest countries. Indeed, my first assignment for the World Bank was to go with Joe to Ethiopia. Since I had just married, the trip was my honeymoon, but with Joe instead of my wife. Fortunately
X PREFACE she was understanding-whether by coincidence or the attraction of like minds,after university she had worked in Malawi. This book is about the Malawis and the Ethiopias of this world,the minority of developing countries that are now at the bottom of the global economic system.Some,such as Malawi,have always been at the bottom. Others,including Sierra Leone,once were less poor than India or China. The countries now at the bottom are distinctive not just in being the poor- est but also in having failed to grow.They are not following the development path of most other nations;they are adrift.As once-poor India and China, and countries like them,surged ahead,the global poverty picture has been confused,concealing this divergent pattern.Of course,for some countries to do relatively better,others must do relatively worse.But the decline of the countries now at the bottom is not just relative;often it is absolute.Many of these countries are not just falling behind,they are falling apart. For the past few years much of my work has been on civil war.I wanted to understand why conflict was increasingly concentrated in low-income Africa.Gradually,I developed the notion of the "conflict trap."It shows how certain economic conditions make a country prone to civil war,and how,once conflict has started,the cycle of violence becomes a trap from which it is difficult to escape.I realized that the conflict trap was one ex- planation for the countries now at the bottom of the world economy.But it was not the whole story.Malawi has been conflict-free for its entire postindependence history,yet it still has not developed.Neither have Kenya and Nigeria,countries on which at different stages in my career I wrote books,and which looked neither like Malawi nor like each other. Nor do I believe that poverty itself is a trap.These development failures occurred against a backdrop of global development success-poverty is something that most people are managing to escape.Since 1980 world poverty has been falling for the first time in history.Nor was it just a mat- ter of Africa.Elsewhere there were also development failures:countries such as Haiti,Laos,Burma,and the Central Asian countries,of which Afghanistan has been the most spectacular.A one-size-fits-all explanation for development failure doesn't ring true against such diversity. Part of the reason single-factor theories about development failure are so common is that modern academics tend to specialize:they are trained to produce intense but narrow beams of light.However,in my career I
she was understanding—whether by coincidence or the attraction of like minds, after university she had worked in Malawi. This book is about the Malawis and the Ethiopias of this world, the minority of developing countries that are now at the bottom of the global economic system. Some, such as Malawi, have always been at the bottom. Others, including Sierra Leone, once were less poor than India or China. The countries now at the bottom are distinctive not just in being the poorest but also in having failed to grow. They are not following the development path of most other nations; they are adrift. As once-poor India and China, and countries like them, surged ahead, the global poverty picture has been confused, concealing this divergent pattern. Of course, for some countries to do relatively better, others must do relatively worse. But the decline of the countries now at the bottom is not just relative; often it is absolute. Many of these countries are not just falling behind, they are falling apart. For the past few years much of my work has been on civil war. I wanted to understand why conflict was increasingly concentrated in low-income Africa. Gradually, I developed the notion of the “conflict trap.” It shows how certain economic conditions make a country prone to civil war, and how, once conflict has started, the cycle of violence becomes a trap from which it is difficult to escape. I realized that the conflict trap was one explanation for the countries now at the bottom of the world economy. But it was not the whole story. Malawi has been conflict-free for its entire postindependence history, yet it still has not developed. Neither have Kenya and Nigeria, countries on which at different stages in my career I wrote books, and which looked neither like Malawi nor like each other. Nor do I believe that poverty itself is a trap. These development failures occurred against a backdrop of global development success—poverty is something that most people are managing to escape. Since 1980 world poverty has been falling for the first time in history. Nor was it just a matter of Africa. Elsewhere there were also development failures: countries such as Haiti, Laos, Burma, and the Central Asian countries, of which Afghanistan has been the most spectacular. A one-size-fits-all explanation for development failure doesn’t ring true against such diversity. Part of the reason single-factor theories about development failure are so common is that modern academics tend to specialize: they are trained to produce intense but narrow beams of light. However, in my career I x PREFACE