Comparative Political Studies http://cps.sagepub.com The Causes of Globalization Geoffrey Garrett Comparative Political Studies 2000;33:941 DO:10.1177/001041400003300610 The online version of this article can be found at: http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/33/6-7/941 Published by: SSAGE Publications http://www.sagepublications.com Additional services and information for Comparative Political Studies can be found at: Email Alerts:http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Subscriptions:http://cps.sagepub.com/subscriptions Reprints:http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Permissions:http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Citations(this article cites 22 articles hosted on the SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms): http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/33/6-7/941 o2oosA8Er6i258osra658PeaeHeC26mer&Y8g6t6298atntbuion
http://cps.sagepub.com Comparative Political Studies DOI: 10.1177/001041400003300610 Comparative Political Studies 2000; 33; 941 Geoffrey Garrett The Causes of Globalization http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/33/6-7/941 The online version of this article can be found at: Published by: http://www.sagepublications.com Additional services and information for Comparative Political Studies can be found at: Email Alerts: http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Subscriptions: http://cps.sagepub.com/subscriptions Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/33/6-7/941 SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms): Citations (this article cites 22 articles hosted on the © 2000 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. Downloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11, 2008
The most important causes of globalization differ among the three major components of interna- tional market integration:trade,multinational production,and intemational finance.The infor- mation technology revolution has made it very difficult for governments to control cross-border capital movements,even if they have political incentives to do so.Governments can still restrict the multinationalization of production,but they have increasingly chosen to liberalize because of the macroeconomic benefits.Although the one-time Ricardian gains from freer trade are clear, whether trade is good for growth in the medium term is less certain.In the case of trade,the increasing interest of exporters in opening up domestic markets has had a powerful impact on the trend to liberalization.Cross-national variations in market integration still endure,but these are more the product of basic economic characteristics (such as country size and level of develop- ment)than political factors(such as regime type or the left-right balance of power). THE CAUSES OF GLOBALIZATION GEOFFREY GARRETT Yale University Theteiithiaosiepmciye equilibrating.But beyond this already trite cliche,almost everything else concerning the phenomenon is subject to intense debate-in the context of an explosion of interest in and research on the subject.1 This article explores what we know about the causes of globalization.In a follow-up article,I will address globalization's consequences for domestic societies(in terms of in- equality and economic insecurity),national autonomy (with respect to regu- lation,spending and taxation,exchange rate regimes,etc.),and international governance (International Monetary Fund [IMF],World Trade Organization [WTO],etc.).Throughout,I define globalization somewhat narrowly as the 1.In 1980.there were fewer than 300 articles or books with the word globalor globalization in the title.In 1995,the number was over 3,000 (Guillen,in press,Table 2). AUTHOR'S NOTE:Thanks to Stephen Brooks,Michael Dooley.Jeffry Frieden,and Ronald Rogowski for helpful discussions on various aspects of this article.I would also like to thank Alexandra Guisinger,Nathan Jensen,Jason Sorens,Andrew Youn,and especially Nancy Brune for invaluable research assistance. COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES,Vol.33 No.6/7,August/September 2000 941-991 2000 Sage Publications.Inc. 941 Dowrloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11.2008 2000 SAGE Publications.All rights reserved.Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution
COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES / August-September 2000 Garrett / CAUSES OF GLOBALIZATION The most important causes of globalization differ among the three major components of international market integration: trade, multinational production, and international finance. The information technology revolution has made it very difficult for governments to control cross-border capital movements, even if they have political incentives to do so. Governments can still restrict the multinationalization of production, but they have increasingly chosen to liberalize because of the macroeconomic benefits. Although the one-time Ricardian gains from freer trade are clear, whether trade is good for growth in the medium term is less certain. In the case of trade, the increasing interest of exporters in opening up domestic markets has had a powerful impact on the trend to liberalization. Cross-national variations in market integration still endure, but these are more the product of basic economic characteristics (such as country size and level of development) than political factors (such as regime type or the left-right balance of power). THE CAUSES OF GLOBALIZATION GEOFFREY GARRETT Yale University There is little disagreement these days that globalization is changing the world rapidly, radically, and in ways that may be profoundly disequilibrating. But beyond this already trite cliché, almost everything else concerning the phenomenon is subject to intense debate—in the context of an explosion of interest in and research on the subject.1 This article explores what we know about the causes of globalization. In a follow-up article, I will address globalization’s consequences for domestic societies (in terms of inequality and economic insecurity), national autonomy (with respect to regulation, spending and taxation, exchange rate regimes, etc.), and international governance (International Monetary Fund [IMF], World Trade Organization [WTO], etc.). Throughout, I define globalization somewhat narrowly as the 941 AUTHOR’S NOTE: Thanks to Stephen Brooks, Michael Dooley, Jeffry Frieden, and Ronald Rogowski for helpful discussions on various aspects of this article. I would also like to thank Alexandra Guisinger, Nathan Jensen, Jason Sorens, Andrew Youn, and especially Nancy Brune for invaluable research assistance. COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES, Vol. 33 No. 6/7, August/September 2000 941-991 © 2000 Sage Publications, Inc. 1. In 1980, there were fewer than 300 articles or books with the word global or globalization in the title. In 1995, the number was over 3,000 (Guillen, in press, Table 2). © 2000 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. Downloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11, 2008
942 COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES/August-September 2000 international integration of markets in goods,services,and capital.Other fac- ets of the phenomenon(such as increased labor mobility and cultural homog- enization)are surely important,but I leave their analysis to others.2 I examine four contending perspectives on the big picture:What explains the rapid pace of international market integration in recent decades?The first perspective claims that what we are witnessing today is,in fact,nothing new because current levels of market integration are only now returning to those in the last great era of economic internationalization at the turn of the 20th century.This view has been accepted as a statement of fact in numerous influ- ential studies (Katzenstein,Keohane,Krasner,1998,p.669;Krasner, 1999,pp.220-223;Rodrik,1997;Sachs Warner,1995).I argue,however, that notwithstanding the aggregate similarities between the two periods,core features of the contemporary world economy are without historical prece- dent.Large-scale portfolio lending to banks in developing countries for pur- poses other than raw material extraction,two-way manufacturing trade between the north and south,and complex multinational production regimes were simply unheard of a century ago. The remaining perspectives on global trends debate the causes of this unprecedented wave of international market integration.The root of the ana- lytic problem lies in the commingling of three secular trends:technological innovations lowering the costs of moving goods and more notably informa- tion around the world,growing international economic activity,and the liber- alization of foreign economic policies.What are the causal relationships among these three trends? The second perspective,technological determinism,contends that the shrinkage of time and space has been so dramatic and so pervasive that there is essentially nothing that can be done to stop it.According to this view,tech- nological changes have propelled international economic activity,and gov- ernments have been largely irrelevant.Thus,policy liberalization should be understood as governments'acknowledging the futility of trying to resist globalization,rather than acting as a prime mover behind market integration. Management gurus such as Ohmae(1995)have propounded this view,and political scientists such as Rosecrance(1999)and Strange(1998)use it as the starting point of their analyses. The case for a technologically determined view of globalization is far stronger with respect to international finance than to multinational produc- tion or trade.In the era of 24-hour global trading in a seemingly limitless array of financial instruments,governments can only hope marginally to influence control cross-border liquid capital movements.In contrast,though 2.See Drezner(1998)and Guillen (in press)for recent reviews of some of these issues. Dowrloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11.2008 2000 SAGE Publications.All rights reserved.Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution
international integration of markets in goods, services, and capital. Other facets of the phenomenon (such as increased labor mobility and cultural homogenization) are surely important, but I leave their analysis to others.2 I examine four contending perspectives on the big picture: What explains the rapid pace of international market integration in recent decades? The first perspective claims that what we are witnessing today is, in fact, nothing new because current levels of market integration are only now returning to those in the last great era of economic internationalization at the turn of the 20th century. This view has been accepted as a statement of fact in numerous influential studies (Katzenstein, Keohane, & Krasner, 1998, p. 669; Krasner, 1999, pp. 220-223; Rodrik, 1997; Sachs & Warner, 1995). I argue, however, that notwithstanding the aggregate similarities between the two periods, core features of the contemporary world economy are without historical precedent. Large-scale portfolio lending to banks in developing countries for purposes other than raw material extraction, two-way manufacturing trade between the north and south, and complex multinational production regimes were simply unheard of a century ago. The remaining perspectives on global trends debate the causes of this unprecedented wave of international market integration. The root of the analytic problem lies in the commingling of three secular trends: technological innovations lowering the costs of moving goods and more notably information around the world, growing international economic activity, and the liberalization of foreign economic policies. What are the causal relationships among these three trends? The second perspective, technological determinism, contends that the shrinkage of time and space has been so dramatic and so pervasive that there is essentially nothing that can be done to stop it. According to this view, technological changes have propelled international economic activity, and governments have been largely irrelevant. Thus, policy liberalization should be understood as governments’ acknowledging the futility of trying to resist globalization, rather than acting as a prime mover behind market integration. Management gurus such as Ohmae (1995) have propounded this view, and political scientists such as Rosecrance (1999) and Strange (1998) use it as the starting point of their analyses. The case for a technologically determined view of globalization is far stronger with respect to international finance than to multinational production or trade. In the era of 24-hour global trading in a seemingly limitless array of financial instruments, governments can only hope marginally to influence control cross-border liquid capital movements. In contrast, though 942 COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES / August-September 2000 2. See Drezner (1998) and Guillen (in press) for recent reviews of some of these issues. © 2000 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. Downloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11, 2008
Garrett CAUSES OF GLOBALIZATION 943 the Internet creates novel problems,it remains easier for governments to reg- ulate cross-border movements of physical goods and the buying and selling of fixed assets.Hence,policy decisions to liberalize trade and foreign direct investment are likely to have been more consequential for international inte- gration in these markets. The third big picture perspective on globalization takes a more moderate view of the effects of technological change.Most mainstream economists (informing the "Washington consensus"and best-sellers;see Yergin Stanislaw,1999)believe that the potential efficiency gains from international integration have increased substantially as a result of technological progress in recent decades.From this perspective,governments can still insulate their countries from external market forces if they so choose.But the "increased opportunity costs of closure"have become sufficiently large to tip the bal- ance in favor of the liberalization of foreign economic policy in country after country. It is hard to argue that increasing opportunity costs of closure provide a persuasive account of the globalization of finance.The hypothetical effi- ciency gains of openness seem in practice to be at least offset by the costs associated with the uncertainty and volatility of international financial mar- kets.At the other end of the spectrum,increasing costs of closure probably have been the major motivation for liberalization in the area of foreign direct investment(FDD).FDI is an important driver of growth.It provides a trans- mission mechanism for the diffusion of technological innovations and less tangible benefits,such as managerial skills.The trade case is less clear-cut. On one hand,there are clearly important one-time gains from trade liberaliza- tion (e.g.,in terms of lowering prices).But modern economic theory is ambiguous as to whether freer trade is beneficial for economic growth,and the empirical evidence is also inconclusive. The final big picture perspective on globalization also accepts the critical role of government policy,but argues that the phenomenon is essentially a political construct that does not improve the economic condition of society as a whole.For example,Rodrik has raised numerous eyebrows among his economist colleagues by claiming that there is no evidence that either freer trade (Rodriguez Rodrik,1999)or capital mobility (Rodrik,1998)is good for economic growth.This is grist for the mill of political scientists such as Helleiner(1994),who propose power and ideology explanations of global- ization.On this"ideological change"view,the roots of contemporary global- ization lay in the neoliberal Reagan/Thatcher revolutions.They were spread throughout the developed world by the European Union(EU)and the Bank of International Settlements,and extended to developing counties by the IMF and the World Bank. Dowrloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11.2008 2000 SAGE Publications.All rights reserved.Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution
the Internet creates novel problems, it remains easier for governments to regulate cross-border movements of physical goods and the buying and selling of fixed assets. Hence, policy decisions to liberalize trade and foreign direct investment are likely to have been more consequential for international integration in these markets. The third big picture perspective on globalization takes a more moderate view of the effects of technological change. Most mainstream economists (informing the “Washington consensus” and best-sellers; see Yergin & Stanislaw, 1999) believe that the potential efficiency gains from international integration have increased substantially as a result of technological progress in recent decades. From this perspective, governments can still insulate their countries from external market forces if they so choose. But the “increased opportunity costs of closure” have become sufficiently large to tip the balance in favor of the liberalization of foreign economic policy in country after country. It is hard to argue that increasing opportunity costs of closure provide a persuasive account of the globalization of finance. The hypothetical efficiency gains of openness seem in practice to be at least offset by the costs associated with the uncertainty and volatility of international financial markets. At the other end of the spectrum, increasing costs of closure probably have been the major motivation for liberalization in the area of foreign direct investment (FDI). FDI is an important driver of growth. It provides a transmission mechanism for the diffusion of technological innovations and less tangible benefits, such as managerial skills. The trade case is less clear-cut. On one hand, there are clearly important one-time gains from trade liberalization (e.g., in terms of lowering prices). But modern economic theory is ambiguous as to whether freer trade is beneficial for economic growth, and the empirical evidence is also inconclusive. The final big picture perspective on globalization also accepts the critical role of government policy, but argues that the phenomenon is essentially a political construct that does not improve the economic condition of society as a whole. For example, Rodrik has raised numerous eyebrows among his economist colleagues by claiming that there is no evidence that either freer trade (Rodriguez & Rodrik, 1999) or capital mobility (Rodrik, 1998) is good for economic growth. This is grist for the mill of political scientists such as Helleiner (1994), who propose power and ideology explanations of globalization. On this “ideological change” view, the roots of contemporary globalization lay in the neoliberal Reagan/Thatcher revolutions. They were spread throughout the developed world by the European Union (EU) and the Bank of International Settlements, and extended to developing counties by the IMF and the World Bank. Garrett / CAUSES OF GLOBALIZATION 943 © 2000 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. Downloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11, 2008
944 COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES/August-September 2000 It is easy,however,to endogenize these ideological changes in terms of technological determinism in international finance and increased opportu- nity costs of closure with respect to multinational production.In the former case,there might be domestic political incentives for governments to main- tain restrictions on cross-border capital movements that are futile in an eco- nomic sense.Such policies send negative signals to the financial markets, however,and many governments may be unwilling to take this risk.In terms of foreign direct investment,the fact that multinational firms have become critical drivers of technological innovation,learning,and economic growth affords them a very "privileged position"(Lindblom,1977)in domestic pol- icy debates. Trade liberalization,in contrast,has not been technologically determined, and the opportunity costs of closure continue to be debated.Changing prefer- ences and coalitional politics may therefore have played a greater role here than with respect to international finance or multinational production.One possible explanation is that exporters have become much more interested in opening their home markets,mitigating the traditional political bias in favor of protection,because of fears of retaliation against them abroad and because many exporters import large portions of the goods they use as inputs in mak- ing finished products. Students of international relations and comparative politics may well object at this point that my analysis gives short shrift to their central concerns and insights.International political economists have devoted enormous attention to cooperative and institutionalized efforts to reduce barriers to international economic exchange among countries.The bread and butter of comparative political economy,on the other hand,concerns explaining cross- national differences in economic policies and outcomes. My general response to these objections is that political scientists tend not to explore in sufficient detail the economics of globalization before they move on to analyzing its politics.Moreover,they have an inherent bias toward assuming both that government policies have real effects and that they are chosen for political reasons.In the case of the trend toward international market integration,it is important to problematize both assumptions.Tech- nological determinists believe that government policy is essentially irrele- vant to globalization;the increased opportunity costs of closure approach suggests that governments have liberalized their economies simply because it is the efficient thing to do.Before asserting that globalization is a political phenomenon,we should assess the merits of these parsimonious explana- tions derived from economic analysis. With respect to international political economy,I do not wish to dispute either that free rider and coordination problems may hinder international Dowrloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11.2008 2000 SAGE Publications.All rights reserved.Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution
It is easy, however, to endogenize these ideological changes in terms of technological determinism in international finance and increased opportunity costs of closure with respect to multinational production. In the former case, there might be domestic political incentives for governments to maintain restrictions on cross-border capital movements that are futile in an economic sense. Such policies send negative signals to the financial markets, however, and many governments may be unwilling to take this risk. In terms of foreign direct investment, the fact that multinational firms have become critical drivers of technological innovation, learning, and economic growth affords them a very “privileged position” (Lindblom, 1977) in domestic policy debates. Trade liberalization, in contrast, has not been technologically determined, and the opportunity costs of closure continue to be debated. Changing preferences and coalitional politics may therefore have played a greater role here than with respect to international finance or multinational production. One possible explanation is that exporters have become much more interested in opening their home markets, mitigating the traditional political bias in favor of protection, because of fears of retaliation against them abroad and because many exporters import large portions of the goods they use as inputs in making finished products. Students of international relations and comparative politics may well object at this point that my analysis gives short shrift to their central concerns and insights. International political economists have devoted enormous attention to cooperative and institutionalized efforts to reduce barriers to international economic exchange among countries. The bread and butter of comparative political economy, on the other hand, concerns explaining crossnational differences in economic policies and outcomes. My general response to these objections is that political scientists tend not to explore in sufficient detail the economics of globalization before they move on to analyzing its politics. Moreover, they have an inherent bias toward assuming both that government policies have real effects and that they are chosen for political reasons. In the case of the trend toward international market integration, it is important to problematize both assumptions. Technological determinists believe that government policy is essentially irrelevant to globalization; the increased opportunity costs of closure approach suggests that governments have liberalized their economies simply because it is the efficient thing to do. Before asserting that globalization is a political phenomenon, we should assess the merits of these parsimonious explanations derived from economic analysis. With respect to international political economy, I do not wish to dispute either that free rider and coordination problems may hinder international 944 COMPARATIVE POLITICAL STUDIES / August-September 2000 © 2000 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. Downloaded from http://cps.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on February 11, 2008