ElectronicjOurnalofcomparativeLa,vol.9.1(january2005),<http://www.ejcl.org/ POSSIBILITIES AND CONSTRAINTSIN THE USE OF SELF-REGULATION AND CO-REGULATION IN LEGISLATIVE POLICY: Experiences in the Netherlands Lessons to be learned for the eu? Philip ejland Readers are reminded that this work is protected by copyright. While they are free to use the ideas expressed in it, they may not copy, distribute or publish the work or part of if, in an form, printed, electronic or otherwise, except for reasonable quoting, clearly indicating the source. Readers are permitted to make copies, electronically or printed, for personal and classroom use Abstract A comparison between the use of self-regulation and co-regulation at the national level and that at the european level is not easy because of the d ifferent functions national legislation and European legislation have On a national scale, the main function of legislation is to achieve uniformity and equality under the law. General rules have a different function in the European Union. The European Union exists thanks to its diversity. The issue of the quality of legislation in the European Union is not a problem of uniformity, but of handling diversity in a well-considered, legal way. In this article, the concepts of self-regulation and co- regulation are analysed, both at the national level(the Netherlands )and at the level of the European Union. Programmes of better law-making propose the use of self-regulation and co-regulation. What can we expect from these proposals? 1. Introduction At the beginning of the 1990s, the Dutch government embarked on an active policy of improving the quality of legislation and the lawmaking process. In the white paper entitle Zicht op wetgeving, the government laid down its plan for the further development and implementation of a general policy on legislation with a view to improving the quality of legislation in terms of constitutional government and proper administration. 2 This document deals with the shortcomings in legislation, mentions the criteria for government action via legislation and contains various action points in general legislative policy One of the fundamental criteria is the principle of subsidiarity. The interaction between government and society is-according to Zicht op wetgeving-very important, also in the preparation and the structure of the legislation. In dutch legislative policy, therefore there is much attention for the concepts of self-regulation and co-regulation. The document Tilbug philip Ejlander is Professor of Legislative Studies and Adm inistrative Law at the Faculty ofLaw of Universit Kamerstukken 1,1990/1991, 22008, nos. 1-2. See also the English version Legislation in Perspective (The Hague: Netherlands Ministry of Justice, 1991)
Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol. 9.1 (January 2005), <http://www.ejcl.org/> 1 POSSIBILITIES AND CONSTRAINTS IN THE USE OF SELF-REGULATION AND CO-REGULATION IN LEGISLATIVE POLICY: Experiences in the Netherlands - Lessons to Be Learned for the EU? Philip Eijlander1 Readers are reminded that this work is protected by copyright. While they are free to use the ideas expressed in it, they may not copy, distribute or publish the work or part of it, in any form, printed, electronic or otherwise, except for reasonable quoting, clearly indicating the source. Readers are permitted to make copies, electronically or printed, for personal and classroom use. Abstract A comparison between the use of self-regulation and co-regulation at the national level and that at the European level is not easy because of the different functions national legislation and European legislation have. On a national scale, the main function of legislation is to achieve uniformity and equality under the law. General rules have a different function in the European Union. The European Union exists thanks to its diversity. The issue of the quality of legislation in the European Union is not a problem of uniformity, but of handling diversity in a well-considered, legal way. In this article, the concepts of self-regulation and coregulation are analysed, both at the national level (the Netherlands) and at the level of the European Union. Programmes of better law-making propose the use of self-regulation and co-regulation. What can we expect from these proposals? 1. Introduction At the beginning of the 1990s, the Dutch government embarked on an active policy of improving the quality of legislation and the lawmaking process. In the white paper entitled Zicht op wetgeving, the government laid down its plan for the further development and implementation of a general policy on legislation with a view to improving the quality of legislation in terms of constitutional government and proper administration.2 This document deals with the shortcomings in legislation, mentions the criteria for government action via legislation and contains various action points in general legislative policy. One of the fundamental criteria is the principle of subsidiarity. The interaction between government and society is - according to Zicht op wetgeving - very important, also in the preparation and the structure of the legislation. In Dutch legislative policy, therefore, there is much attention for the concepts of self-regulation and co-regulation. The document 1 Philip Eijlander is Professor of Legislative Studies and Administrative Law at the Faculty of Law of Tilburg University. 2 Kamerstukken II, 1990/1991, 22 008, nos. 1-2. See also the English version Legislation in Perspective (The Hague: Netherlands Ministry of Justice, 1991)
ElectronicjournalofcomparatIveLaw,vol.9.1(january2005),<http://www.ejclorg/- states: The legislator can sometimes suffice with providing a framework and checking the outcome afterward. It is necessary to strike a proper balance between government regulation as an expression of government responsibility, and self-regulation by the people and by social organisations within this framework legally structured and conditioned self-regulation. 3 agreement concluded by the European Parliament the Council and the Europeal eA4Thi In 2003, the Interinstitutional Agreement on better law-making was publish Commission aims to improve the quality of regulations in the European Union. Like the Dutch white paper Zicht op wetgeving, this European agreement on better law-making pays attention to alternative forms of regulation, such as self-regulation and co-regulation The main question addressed in this article is: What can we learn from the experiences in the Netherlands in connection with the European policy on improving the quality of legislation and the use of self-regulation? Can we compare European legislative policy with a national policy on this issue? First, I will go into the concept of self-regulation (section 2). Next, the motives and forms of self-regulation will be analysed and the situation in the Netherlands will be compared with the use of self-regulation in the European Union (section 3). In section 4, I will discuss the proposals of the better law-making programme Finally, I will present some conclusions on the possibilities for and the constraints on the use of self-regulation in legislative policy(section 5) 2. The concept of self-regulation Self-regulation can be seen as an alternative to so-called command-and-control regulation The essence of command-and-control regulation is the exercise of influence by imposing standards backed by sanctions. The assumption that government can exercise influence and control over the behaviour of citizens and companies merely by setting up central rules and regulations is based on an overestimation of the position of government in our complex information society. Therefore, in legislative policy it is recognised that the responsibility of authorities does not imply per se that government bodies must always make all the rules and see to their implementation. More often than not it will be sufficient for the legislature to provide a framework for self-regulation by social organisations Self-regulation in its pure form can be defined as regulation by organisations or associations in a field of society; not only do they create the rules, but they also monitor compliance with these rules and enforce them against their own members. Thus, we can state three essential characteristics of self-regulation It concerns the regulation and ordering of behaviour in a certain group of society It consists in rules which have been laid down for and work within the group These rules can be enforced aga inst the group mem bers Legislation in Perspective, p. 2 OJ2003.C321/01 See robert Baldwin and Martin Cave, Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy, and Practice (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), p 35
Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol. 9.1 (January 2005), <http://www.ejcl.org/> 2 states: ‘The legislator can sometimes suffice with providing a framework and checking the outcome afterward. It is necessary to strike a proper balance between government regulation, as an expression of government responsibility, and self-regulation by the people and by social organisations within this framework: legally structured and conditioned self-regulation.’3 In 2003, the Interinstitutional Agreement on better law-making was published.4 This agreement concluded by the European Parliament, the Council and the European Commission aims to improve the quality of regulations in the European Union. Like the Dutch white paper Zicht op wetgeving, this European agreement on better law-making pays attention to alternative forms of regulation, such as self-regulation and co-regulation. The main question addressed in this article is: What can we learn from the experiences in the Netherlands in connection with the European policy on improving the quality of legislation and the use of self-regulation? Can we compare European legislative policy with a national policy on this issue? First, I will go into the concept of self-regulation (section 2). Next, the motives and forms of self-regulation will be analysed and the situation in the Netherlands will be compared with the use of self-regulation in the European Union (section 3). In section 4, I will discuss the proposals of the better law-making programme. Finally, I will present some conclusions on the possibilities for and the constraints on the use of self-regulation in legislative policy (section 5). 2. The concept of self-regulation Self-regulation can be seen as an alternative to so-called command-and-control regulation. The essence of command-and-control regulation is the exercise of influence by imposing standards backed by sanctions.5 The assumption that government can exercise influence and control over the behaviour of citizens and companies merely by setting up central rules and regulations is based on an overestimation of the position of government in our complex information society. Therefore, in legislative policy it is recognised that the responsibility of authorities does not imply per se that government bodies must always make all the rules and see to their implementation. More often than not it will be sufficient for the legislature to provide a framework for self-regulation by social organisations. Self-regulation in its pure form can be defined as regulation by organisations or associations in a field of society; not only do they create the rules, but they also monitor compliance with these rules and enforce them against their own members. Thus, we can state three essential characteristics of self-regulation: - It concerns the regulation and ordering of behaviour in a certain group of society. - It consists in rules which have been laid down for and work within the group. - These rules can be enforced against the group members. 3 Legislation in Perspective, p. 22. 4 OJ 2003, C 321/01. 5 See Robert Baldwin and Martin Cave, Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy, and Practice (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), p. 35
ElectronicJournalofcomparativeLaww,vol.9.1(jAnuary2005),<http://www.ejcl.org/> An example of self-regulation in this sense are the codes of conduct in groups o professionals which can be enforced by an association, for example in the fields of health care and insurances Self-regulation differs from related concepts such as deregulation and co-regulation various ways. Deregulation means that the central rules from government are minimised which results in more alternatives for citizens and enterprises. this does not need to result in the group or sector itself drawing up extra rules An essential aspect of co-regulation is the cooperation between the public and the private actors in the process of creating new rules. This fits into the concept of the network society, in which it is necessary to gather one's strength, also in the field of regulation. This cooperation in the field of regulation may, however, result in various forms, such as agreements, conventions and even regular legislation. In the last case, this government regulation is the result of a process of negotiating between the public and the private parties nvolved 3. Motives for and types of self-regulation Self-regulation is not necessarily related to public regulation; self-regulation may also be an alternative to legislation. In the latter case, public regulation is appropriate because of the expectation that with certain forms of self-regulation the same or better results can be achieved. However, self-regulation may also come into being without any threat of public regulation. In a particular sector or branch, the need for group rules' may arise in the interest of the group itself, such as the image of the group or for the sake of the clientstrust in the quality of the products or the service An Australian report on self-regulation in industry and business mentions the following motives for self-regulation to raise industry standards to use it as a marketing tool; to enhance the level of information to avoid govemment regulation to meet legislative requirements a combination of the above factors 6 An essential aspect is the distinction between private and public motives for the use of self- regulation and the possible relation between these sorts of motives. In the field of economics the public- interest and the private-interest approaches in regulation theory are well-known. 7 The public-interest approach focuses on the regulation of markets to increase social welfar while the private-interest approach is concerned with the study of the position of interest groups in the process of regulation. An element in the latter approach is the concern that the relationships between the regulators and the regulated may become too close and thus lead to Seehttp://www.selfregulation.govau/publications(acCessedJuly2003) See J.A.H. Maks, M. Faure andN Philipsen, Zelfregulering, marktwerking en mededinging availablethroughhttp:/www.minez.nl
Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol. 9.1 (January 2005), <http://www.ejcl.org/> 3 An example of self-regulation in this sense are the codes of conduct in groups of professionals which can be enforced by an association, for example in the fields of health care and insurances. Self-regulation differs from related concepts such as deregulation and co-regulation in various ways. Deregulation means that the central rules from government are minimised, which results in more alternatives for citizens and enterprises. This does not need to result in the group or sector itself drawing up extra rules. An essential aspect of co-regulation is the cooperation between the public and the private actors in the process of creating new rules. This fits into the concept of the network society, in which it is necessary to gather one’s strength, also in the field of regulation. This cooperation in the field of regulation may, however, result in various forms, such as agreements, conventions and even regular legislation. In the last case, this government regulation is the result of a process of negotiating between the public and the private parties involved. 3. Motives for and types of self-regulation Self-regulation is not necessarily related to public regulation; self-regulation may also be an alternative to legislation. In the latter case, public regulation is appropriate because of the expectation that with certain forms of self-regulation the same or better results can be achieved. However, self-regulation may also come into being without any threat of public regulation. In a particular sector or branch, the need for ‘group rules’ may arise in the interest of the group itself, such as the image of the group or for the sake of the clients’ trust in the quality of the products or the service. An Australian report on self-regulation in industry and business mentions the following motives for self-regulation: - to raise industry standards; - to use it as a marketing tool; - to enhance the level of information; - to avoid government regulation; - to meet legislative requirements; - a combination of the above factors.6 An essential aspect is the distinction between private and public motives for the use of selfregulation and the possible relation between these sorts of motives. In the field of economics, the public-interest and the private-interest approaches in regulation theory are well-known.7 The public-interest approach focuses on the regulation of markets to increase social welfare, while the private-interest approach is concerned with the study of the position of interest groups in the process of regulation. An element in the latter approach is the concern that the relationships between the regulators and the regulated may become too close and thus lead to 6 See http://www.selfregulation.gov.au/Publications (accessed July 2003). 7 See J.A.H. Maks, M. Faure and N. Philipsen, ‘Zelfregulering, marktwerking en mededinging’, available through http://www.minez.nl
ElectronicjournalofcomparaTiveLaw,vol.9.1(january2005),<http://www.ejcl.org large. A nu pursuit of the regulated enterprises'interests rather than those of the public at capture umber of versions of the capture theory have been put forward. 8 In practice, it is a challenge to make the connection between the private motives for the use of self-regulation and the public interests that are or can be at issue. In relation to this we introduce the following three categories of self-regulation: free or pure self-regulation, substitute or alternative self-regulation and cond itioned self-regulation. 9 In the situation of pure self-regulation, the initiative is fully with the private parties in the relevant field government is not involved and accepts the result as long as it is not against certain general rules such as those on fair competition. The substitute type of self-regulation concerns the situation in which the initiative is on the side of the private actors, but government watches the process in order to safeguard the public interest that may be at stake. This may be the cas n the field of consumers rights. Cond itioned self-regulation means that public and private rules are intertwined. Here, self-regulation is subject to a type of government structuring or oversight. Baldwin and Cave(1999)mention the following ad vantages of this cond itioned or enforced self-regulation as compared to trad itional command-and-control regulation the high level of comm tment of firms and associations to ' their own' rules well-informed rule-making low costs to govemment; a close fit between regulation and the standards firms accept as realistically attainable, greater effectiveness in detecting violations and in securing convictions where prosecution is he greater comprehensiveness of rules the potentialof self-regulatory rules for rapid adjustment to changingcircumstances more effective complaints procedures. 10 On the other hand there is also concern about the use of cond itioned self-regulation The costs to the public purse of approving self-regulatory rules may be considerable The rules written by self-regulators may prove self-serving and may not be immune from the problems afflicting in command and control regimes The procedures employed to produce rules may be subject to the objection that they lack openness, transparency, accountability and acceptability to the public and to consumers of services Compliance units within firms may not always retain their independence and the public may not trust self-regulatory bodies to apply the rules in the public or consumer interest Where self-regulatory regimes conta n powers to make and enforce rules and to sanction transgressors, difficult doctrinal questions may arise as to their broadersubjection to the principles of administrative The public may demand that the govemment take responsibility for a sector or an issue See, e.g., B Mitnick, The Political Economy of Regulation: Creating, Designing, and Removin Regulatory Forms(New York/Guildford: Columbia University Press, 1980) Introduced by A Geelhoed, Deregulering, herregulering en zelfregulering,, in P. Eijlander, P C Gilhuis and J. A F. Peters(eds ) Overheid en =elfregulering. Alibi voor vrijblijvendheid ofprikkel tot aktie? Zwolle: W.E.J. Tjeenk willink, 1993), pp 33-52 Baldwin and Cave(1999), pp 40f. 4
Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol. 9.1 (January 2005), <http://www.ejcl.org/> 4 capture - the pursuit of the regulated enterprises’ interests rather than those of the public at large. A number of versions of the capture theory have been put forward.8 In practice, it is a challenge to make the connection between the private motives for the use of self-regulation and the public interests that are or can be at issue. In relation to this, we introduce the following three categories of self-regulation: free or pure self-regulation, substitute or alternative self-regulation and conditioned self-regulation.9 In the situation of pure self-regulation, the initiative is fully with the private parties in the relevant field; government is not involved and accepts the result as long as it is not against certain general rules such as those on fair competition. The substitute type of self-regulation concerns the situation in which the initiative is on the side of the private actors, but government watches the process in order to safeguard the public interest that may be at stake. This may be the case in the field of consumers rights. Conditioned self-regulation means that public and private rules are intertwined. Here, self-regulation is subject to a type of government structuring or oversight. Baldwin and Cave (1999) mention the following advantages of this conditioned or enforced self-regulation as compared to traditional command-and-control regulation: - the high level of commitment of firms and associations to ‘their own’ rules; - well-informed rule-making; - low costs to government; - a close fit between regulation and the standards firms accept as realistically attainable; - greater effectiveness in detecting violations and in securing convictions where prosecution is necessary; - the greater comprehensiveness of rules; - the potential of self-regulatory rules for rapid adjustment to changing circumstances; - more effective complaints procedures.10 On the other hand, there is also concern about the use of conditioned self-regulation: - The costs to the public purse of approving self-regulatory rules may be considerable. - The rules written by self-regulators may prove self-serving and may not be immune from the problems afflicting in command and control regimes. - The procedures employed to produce rules may be subject to the objection that they lack openness, transparency, accountability and acceptability to the public and to consumers of services. - Compliance units within firms may not always retain their independence and the public may not trust self-regulatory bodies to apply the rules in the public or consumer interest. - Where self-regulatory regimes contain powers to make and enforce rules and to sanction transgressors, difficult doctrinal questions may arise as to their broader subjection to the principles of administrative law. - The public may demand that the government take responsibility for a sector or an issue. 8 See, e.g., B. Mitnick, The Political Economy of Regulation: Creating, Designing, and Removing Regulatory Forms (New York/Guildford: Columbia University Press, 1980). 9 Introduced by A. Geelhoed, ‘Deregulering, herregulering en zelfregulering’, in P. Eijlander, P.C. Gilhuis and J.A.F. Peters (eds.), Overheid en zelfregulering. Alibi voor vrijblijvendheid of prikkel tot aktie? (Zwolle: W.E.J. Tjeenk Willink, 1993), pp. 33-52. 10 Baldwin and Cave (1999), pp. 40 f
ElectronicjournalofcomparatIveLa,vol.9.1(january2005),<http://www.ejcl.org Cond itioned self-regulation can be functional in situations where combinations of regulatory strategies are employed. An example in Dutch legislation concerns the regulation of the quality of health-care institutes and services. The Kwaliteitswet zorginstellingen(Care Institutions(Quality) Act) provides a general frame for the regulation of this field, and within this frame it is up to the actors in the sector to give interpretation to the general rules. In the last resort, the public Inspectie voor de Gerondheidszorg(Health-Care Inspectorate)monitors the acts of the institutes and personal services. 2 Also in other sectors of public service in the Netherlands this type of self-regulation is and can be used here, the differences between the public interest and the standards of the professionals in the field do not differ greatly 4. Better regulation During the last decade, more attention has been paid to improving the quality of European legislation within the framework of European governance. Since the Lisbon European Council in particular, good European legislation-which is mindful of the principles of subsid iarity and proportionality -has been perceived as an issue; see, for example, the Action plan "Simplifying and improving the regulatory environment,. 4 In this plan, the Commission mentions self-regulation as one of the appropriate legislative instruments. According to the Commission, self-regulation concerns a large number of practices, common rules, codes of conduct and voluntary agreements which economic actors, social players, NGOs and organised groups establish on a voluntary basis in order to regulate and organise thei activities 15 Co-regulation enables actors to ensure that the objectives defined by the legislature can be achieved in the context of measures carried out by parties recognised within the field of regulation concerned. The Action plan provides a framework for the use of co-regulation Co-regulation can be used on the basis of a legislative act. The co-regulation mechanism must be in the interest of the general public The legislature establishes the essential aspects of the regulation The legislature determ ines to what extent defining and implementing the measures ca n be left to the parties concerned In cases where using the co-regulation mechanism has not produced the expected rules, the right reserved to make a traditional legislative proposal The principle of transparency of legislation applies to the co-regulation mechanism Sectoral agreements and moda lities for implementation must be made public Ibid. p 41 See P. Erlander, Zelfregulering en wetgevingsbeleid,, in Eij lander, Gilhuis and Peters(1993), pp 129-140 3 See P. Eijlander and R.G. Lauwerier, Regulering van het bestuur van de maatschappelijke dienstverlening.Eenheidinverscheidenheid?,,http:/wwwwr.nlpublicatieinformatie.php?publicatieid=465 COM(2002)278 final Ibid. p 11
Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol. 9.1 (January 2005), <http://www.ejcl.org/> 5 Conditioned self-regulation can be functional in situations where combinations of regulatory strategies are employed.11 An example in Dutch legislation concerns the regulation of the quality of health-care institutes and services. The Kwaliteitswet zorginstellingen (Care Institutions (Quality) Act) provides a general frame for the regulation of this field, and within this frame it is up to the actors in the sector to give interpretation to the general rules. In the last resort, the public Inspectie voor de Gezondheidszorg (Health-Care Inspectorate) monitors the acts of the institutes and personal services.12 Also in other sectors of public service in the Netherlands this type of self-regulation is and can be used;13 here, the differences between the public interest and the standards of the professionals in the field do not differ greatly. 4. Better regulation During the last decade, more attention has been paid to improving the quality of European legislation within the framework of European governance. Since the Lisbon European Council in particular, good European legislation - which is mindful of the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality - has been perceived as an issue; see, for example, the Action plan ‘Simplifying and improving the regulatory environment’.14 In this plan, the Commission mentions self-regulation as one of the appropriate legislative instruments. According to the Commission, self-regulation concerns a large number of practices, common rules, codes of conduct and voluntary agreements which economic actors, social players, NGOs and organised groups establish on a voluntary basis in order to regulate and organise their activities.15 Co-regulation enables actors to ensure that the objectives defined by the legislature can be achieved in the context of measures carried out by parties recognised within the field of regulation concerned. The Action plan provides a framework for the use of co-regulation: - Co-regulation can be used on the basis of a legislative act. - The co-regulation mechanism must be in the interest of the general public. - The legislature establishes the essential aspects of the regulation. - The legislature determines to what extent defining and implementing the measures ca n be left to the parties concerned. - In cases where using the co-regulation mechanism has not produced the expected rules, the right is reserved to make a traditional legislative proposal. - The principle of transparency of legislation applies to the co-regulation mechanism. Sectoral agreements and modalities for implementation must be made public. 11 Ibid., p. 41. 12 See P. Eijlander, ‘Zelfregulering en wetgevingsbeleid’, in Eijlander, Gilhuis and Peters (1993), pp. 129-140. 13 See P. Eijlander and R.G. Lauwerier, ‘Regulering van het bestuur van de maatschappelijke dienstverlening. Eenheid in verscheidenheid?’, http://www.wrr.nl/publicatieinformatie.php?publicatieid=465. 14 COM(2002) 278 final. 15 Ibid., p. 11