Things That Go Bump in the Flight 273 Things That go Bump in the Flight Krista m. dowe Nathan m. Gossett Mark p. leverentz Bethel College St Paul, MN Advisor: William M. Kinney Introduction We develop a risk assessment model that allows an airline to specify certain arameters and receive recommendations for compensation policy for bumped passengers and for how much to overbook each flight. The basis is the potential cost each bumped passenger compared to the potential revenue from booking an extra passenger. Our model allows an airline to compare quickly the likel results of different compensation and overbooking strategies To demonstrate how our model works, we apply it to Vanguard Airlines Publicly available data provide all of the needed parameters for our model. Our software package reaches an overbooking policy by calculating and comparing the expected revenues for all possible situations and compensation policies Terms and definitions We set out terminology, taking much of it from Delta Airlines [2002] Available seat miles (ASM): A measure of capacity which is calculated by multiplying the total number of seats available for transporting passengers by the total number of miles flown during a reporting period Revenue passenger mile(RPM): One revenue-paying passenger transported gers by the number of miles they are flown for the reporting perri passen- one mile. RPM is calculated by multiplying the number of revenue Load factor (LF): A measure of aircraft utilization for a reporting period, cal- culated by dividing RPm by ASM The UMAP Journal 23(3)(2002)273-282. Copyright 2002 by COMAP, Inc. Allrights reserved Permission to make digital or hard copies of part or all of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial dvantage and that copies bear this notice. Abstracting with credit is permitted, but copyrights for components of this work owned by others than COMAP must be honored. To copy otherwise, to republish, to post on servers, or to redistribute to lists requires prior permission from COMAP
Things That Go Bump in the Flight 273 Things That Go Bump in the Flight Krista M. Dowdey Nathan M. Gossett Mark P. Leverentz Bethel College St. Paul, MN Advisor: William M. Kinney Introduction We develop a risk assessment model that allows an airline to specify certain parameters and receive recommendations for compensation policy for bumped passengers and for how much to overbook each flight. The basis is the potential cost of each bumped passenger compared to the potential revenue from booking an extra passenger. Our model allows an airline to compare quickly the likely results of different compensation and overbooking strategies. To demonstrate how our model works, we apply it to Vanguard Airlines. Publicly available data provide all of the needed parameters for our model. Our software package reaches an overbooking policy by calculating and comparing the expected revenues for all possible situations and compensation policies. Terms and Definitions We set out terminology, taking much of it from Delta Airlines [2002]. • Available seat miles (ASM): A measure of capacity which is calculated by multiplying the total number of seats available for transporting passengers by the total number of miles flown during a reporting period. • Revenue passenger mile (RPM): One revenue-paying passenger transported one mile. RPM is calculated by multiplying the number of revenue passengers by the number of miles they are flown for the reporting period. • Load factor (LF):A measure of aircraft utilization for a reporting period, calculated by dividing RPM by ASM. The UMAP Journal 23 (3) (2002) 273–282. c Copyright 2002 by COMAP, Inc. All rights reserved. Permission to make digital or hard copies of part or all of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies bear this notice. Abstracting with credit is permitted, but copyrights for components of this work owned by others than COMAP must be honored. To copy otherwise, to republish, to post on servers, or to redistribute to lists requires prior permission from COMAP
274 The UMAP Journal 23.3(2002) during a reporting period; also referred to as umit cay er available seat mile Cost per available seat mile( CASM): Operating cost pe Revenue per available seat mile (rasm): Total revenue for a reporting period divided by available seat miles; also referred to as unit revenue ."No-show: A person who purchased a ticket but does not attempt to board the intended flight Bumping: The practice of denying boarding to a ticket holder due to lack of sufficient seating on the flight Voluntary bumping: When passengers who purchased ticket for a flight give up their seats for some compensation offered by the airline Involuntary bumping: When not enough passengers voluntarily give up their seats, the airline chooses whom to bump against their will Revenue: Money gained by the airline from a flight minus penalties paid to bumped passengers. This is not the standard definition of revenue("inflow of assets as result of sales of goods and/or services"[Porter 2001, 1461). We use this different definition to highlight the effect of bumping practices Flight leg: a direct flight from one airport to another with no stops Assumptions Passenger airline traffic is returning to normal, so yearly industry statistics can be used. Airline traffic trends are returning to the levels before the terrorist attacks on September 11 [Airline Transport Association 2001],so statistics from before that date are still valid We model U.S. flights only. International flights have different policies The"no-show rate is about 10%. ["More airline passengers .. " 1999] Ticket prices may be represented by calculated averages. The number of passengers on the plane does not affect the cost of the flight to the airline. The most significant part of the operating costs for a flight are fixed costs that are not be affected by the number of passengers The flight schedule is static. The schedule of flights is outside of the scope of our problem statement. Thus, we make recommendations only about the overbooking strategy, not about changes to the schedule Airlines must follow the dOtFly-Rights"regulations. These regula tions outline the minimal compensation required to passengers when bump- ing occurs [U.S. Department of Transportation 1994
274 The UMAP Journal 23.3 (2002) • Cost per available seat mile (CASM): Operating cost per available seat mile during a reporting period; also referred to as unit cost. • Revenue per available seat mile (RASM): Total revenue for a reporting period divided by available seat miles; also referred to as unit revenue. • “No-show”: A person who purchased a ticket but does not attempt to board the intended flight. • Bumping: The practice of denying boarding to a ticket holder due to lack of sufficient seating on the flight. • Voluntary bumping: When passengers who purchased ticket for a flight give up their seats for some compensation offered by the airline. • Involuntary bumping: When not enough passengers voluntarily give up their seats, the airline chooses whom to bump against their will. • Revenue: Money gained by the airline from a flight minus penalties paid to bumped passengers. This is notthe standard definition of revenue (“inflow of assets as result of sales of goods and/or services” [Porter 2001, 146]). We use this different definition to highlight the effect of bumping practices.) • Flight leg: A direct flight from one airport to another with no stops. Assumptions • Passenger airline traffic is returning to normal, so yearly industry statistics can be used. Airline traffic trends are returning to the levels before the terrorist attacks on September 11 [Airline Transport Association 2001], so statistics from before that date are still valid. • We model U.S. flights only. International flights have different policies. • The “no-show” rate is about 10%. [“More airline passengers ... ” 1999]. • Ticket prices may be represented by calculated averages. • The number of passengers on the plane does not affect the cost of the flight to the airline. The most significant part of the operating costs for a flight are fixed costs that are not be affected by the number of passengers. • The flight schedule is static. The schedule of flights is outside of the scope of our problem statement. Thus, we make recommendations only about the overbooking strategy, not about changes to the schedule. • Airlines must follow the DOT “Fly-Rights” regulations. These regulations outline the minimal compensation required to passengers when bumping occurs [U.S. Department of Transportation 1994]
Things That Go Bump in the Flight 275 Compounded overbooking takes care of itself (i.e goes away naturally) Consistentindustry-wide statistics establish a 60% to 80% load factor [Airline Transport Association 2002, resulting in naturally combating the waterfall effect of one overbooked flight causing another to be even more overbooked There is sufficient demand for at least some flights to warrant overbooking. No-shows do not generate revenue. No-shows are given a refund or (if original ticket was nonrefundable)a ticket voucher. Taxes paid by a passenger are nonrefundable Statement of Purpose e Our first priority is to maximize revenue for the airline Our second priority is to maximize customer service in the form of providing as much compensation to bumped passengers as is financially feasible Naive model The naive approach is to assume that since not all ticket buyers show up for the flight, we simply overbook the flight so that on average the plane fills to capacity. If on average 90% show up, we book to 100/90 capacity. However, the 90% is only an average; for some flights, more than 90% will ow up, resulting in bumped passengers and a penalty for the airline paid to bumped passengers. Since the penalty is often more than the potential revenu for one more passenger, the airline could pay more in penalties than the extra revenue received. We need a way to factor the risk of penalties into our model Risk assessment Model We maximize revenue on each individual flight leg, which we regard as independent of other flight legs. Thus, optimizing the revenue of one flight does not adversely affect potential revenue from other flights Since an airline incurs an increased penalty the longer that a bumped passen ger is delayed, an airline minimizes the penalty by transporting the passenger their destination as qu possible. Therefore, bumped usually booked on the next flight or series of flights to their destination
Things That Go Bump in the Flight 275 • Compounded overbooking takes care of itself (i.e., goes away naturally). Consistent industry-wide statistics establish a 60% to 80% load factor [Airline Transport Association 2002], resulting in naturally combating the waterfall effect of one overbooked flight causing another to be even more overbooked. • There is sufficient demand for at least someflights to warrant overbooking. • No-shows do not generate revenue. No-shows are given a refund or (if original ticket was nonrefundable) a ticket voucher. • Taxes paid by a passenger are nonrefundable. Statement of Purpose • Our first priority is to maximize revenue for the airline. • Our second priority is to maximize customer service in the form of providing as much compensation to bumped passengers as is financially feasible. Naive Model The naive approach is to assume that since not all ticket buyers show up for the flight, we simply overbook the flight so that on average the plane fills to capacity. If on average 90% show up, we book to 100/90 capacity. However, the 90% is only an average; for some flights, more than 90% will show up, resulting in bumped passengers and a penalty for the airline paid to bumped passengers. Since the penalty is often more than the potential revenue for one more passenger, the airline could pay more in penalties than the extra revenue received. We need a way to factor the risk of penalties into our model. Risk Assessment Model We maximize revenue on each individual flight leg, which we regard as independent of other flight legs. Thus, optimizing the revenue of one flight does not adversely affect potential revenue from other flights. Since an airline incurs an increased penalty the longer that a bumped passenger is delayed, an airline minimizes the penalty by transporting the passenger to their destination as quickly as possible. Therefore, bumped passengers are usually booked on the next flight or series of flights to their destination
276 The UMAP Journal 23.3(2002) Expected Revenue of a Flight Let a flight have capacity of c and we book b passengers. Let r be the poten- tial revenue from a passenger and p the potential penalty cost of a passenger bumped. Finally, let z be the percentage of ticket holders who show up for the flight. The revenue generated by the flight is if rb< c revenue(al cr-(ab-c)p, if xb>c. The percentage a of passengers who show up follows some probability distri- bution with density function f(a)and an appropriate mean(in our case, 0.9) We find the value of b that maximizes the expected revenue for b passengers expected- revenue(b) f(ar). revenue(a, b)dr Repeat this process for all flights and you have a complete recommendation for an overbooking policy. Examining Compensation Policies We can adjust our model even further by examining the effects of different compensation policies. Airlines have several forms of compensation at their disposal, from food to hotel stays to vouchers. The cost of the compensation policy is the penalty paid to a bumped passenger(p in our formulas above) By rerunning our expected revenue calculations for each compensation policy, we can see how each policy affects the maximum expected revenue of a flight Key Overbooking Flights An airline can determine from historical data the"key"overbooking flights, the ones most likely to require overbooking. It can then use a compensation policy that concentrates on maximizing expected revenue for those flights From Theory to Reality: Vanguard airlines We illustrate our ideas by a case study of Vanguard Airlines, using publicly available information below [Vanguard Airlines 2001]. We assume that the January 2001 through September 2001 statistics provide an accurate picture of he airline RASM= $0.073/seat-mile RPM=817 330 passenger-miles
276 The UMAP Journal 23.3 (2002) Expected Revenue of a Flight Let a flight have capacity of c and we book b passengers. Let r be the potential revenue from a passenger and p the potential penalty cost of a passenger bumped . Finally, let x be the percentage of ticket holders who show up for the flight. The revenue generated by the flight is revenue(x, b) = xbr, if xb ≤ c; cr − (xb − c)p, if xb > c. The percentage x of passengers who show up follows some probability distribution with density function f(x) and an appropriate mean (in our case, 0.9). We find the value of b that maximizes the expected revenue for b passengers: expected revenue(b) = 1 0 f(x) · revenue(x, b) dx Repeat this process for all flights and you have a complete recommendation for an overbooking policy. Examining Compensation Policies We can adjust our model even further by examining the effects of different compensation policies. Airlines have several forms of compensation at their disposal, from food to hotel stays to vouchers. The cost of the compensation policy is the penalty paid to a bumped passenger (p in our formulas above). By rerunning our expected revenue calculations for each compensation policy, we can see how each policy affects the maximum expected revenue of a flight. Key Overbooking Flights An airline can determine from historical data the “key” overbooking flights, the ones most likely to require overbooking. It can then use a compensation policy that concentrates on maximizing expected revenue for those flights. From Theory to Reality: Vanguard Airlines We illustrate our ideas by a case study of Vanguard Airlines, using publicly available information below [Vanguard Airlines 2001]. We assume that the January 2001 through September 2001 statistics provide an accurate picture of the airline: • RASM = $ 0.073/seat-mile. • RPM = 817,330 passenger-miles.
Things That Go Bump in the Flight 277 ASM=1,225,942 seat-miles Operating expenses per ASM=$0.090/seat-mile A full flight(Boeing 737-200 or MD-80 aircraft) holds c= 130 passengers 95% of bumped passengers are volunteers [U.S. Department of Transporta tion 20011 Applying the model We created a software packag e paramete rized for adaptation to any airline Vanguards web site[2002] gives a list of flight legs, along with source cities, destination cities, departure times, and arrival times. All flight legs are flown daily, except for four; to keep our example simple, we ignore these exceptions and treat all flights as daily The potential revenue r per passenger is the average ticket price for the flight leg, we calculate it as flight-leg distance times revenue earned per passenger mile. The latter is total revenue(rASm x ASM) divided by passenger-miles flown(RPM). So we have (distance)(RASM)(ASM) RPM We could not locate good data on the distribution of how many ticket buyers show up for the flight. In lieu of a real distribution, we use a truncated normal distribution with mean 0.9 and appropriately small standard deviation(0.05) 1.023 0.05√2丌 Penalty costs depend on how long the passenger is delayed, so we search the flight schedule for the quickest alternative route for each flight leg. W require at least 30 min between connecting flights Compensation Policies There are three main forms of compensating bumped passengers Cash Payment vs Ticket Voucher ers who arrive at their destination within one hour of their originally scheduled arrival receive no compensation Those who arrive between one and two hours after their originally sched- uled arrival are eligible for compensation in the amount of their full ticket cost up to $200
Things That Go Bump in the Flight 277 • ASM = 1,225,942 seat-miles. • Operating expenses per ASM = $ 0.090/seat-mile. • A full flight (Boeing 737-200 or MD-80 aircraft) holds c = 130 passengers. • 95% of bumped passengers are volunteers [U.S. Department of Transportation 2001]. Applying the Model We created a software package parameterized for adaptation to any airline. Vanguard’s web site [2002] gives a list of flight legs, along with source cities, destination cities, departure times, and arrival times. All flight legs are flown daily, except for four; to keep our example simple, we ignore these exceptions and treat all flights as daily. The potential revenue r per passenger is the average ticket price for the flight leg; we calculate it as flight-leg distance times revenue earned per passenger mile. The latter is total revenue (RASM × ASM) divided by passenger-miles flown (RPM). So we have r = (distance)(RASM)(ASM) RPM . We could not locate good data on the distribution of how many ticket buyers show up for the flight. In lieu of a real distribution, we use a truncated normal distribution with mean 0.9 and appropriately small standard deviation (0.05): f(x) = 1.023 0.05√2π e200(x−0.9)2 . Penalty costs depend on how long the passenger is delayed, so we search the flight schedule for the quickest alternative route for each flight leg. We require at least 30 min between connecting flights. Compensation Policies There are three main forms of compensating bumped passengers: • Cash Payment vs. Ticket Voucher – Bumped passengers who arrive at their destination within one hour of their originally scheduled arrival receive no compensation. – Those who arrive between one and two hours after their originally scheduled arrival are eligible for compensation in the amount of their full ticket cost up to $200