Eficient Capital Markets 387 course sa Lys much more than the general expected return model summarized by (1). For example, if we restrict (1)by assuming that the expected return on security j is constant over time, then we have f, t+19t says that the mean of the distribution of r, t +1 is independent of the in- nation available at t, t, whereas the random walk model of (7) in addi tion says that the entire distribution is independent of e.5 We argue later that it is best to regard the random walk model as an extension of the general expected return or fair game?efficient markets model in the sense of making a more detailed statement about the economic environment. The "fair game "model just says that the conditions of market equilibrium can be stated in terms of expected returns, and thus it says little about the details of the stochastic process generating returns. a random walk arises within the context of such a model when the environment is(fortu- itously )such that the evolution of investor tastes and the process generating new information combine to produce equilibria in which return distributions repeat themselves through time Thus it is not surprising that empirical tests of the "random walk"model that are in fact tests of "fair game"properties are more strongly in support of the model than tests of the additional(and, from the viewpoint of expected return market efficiency, superfluous)pure independence assumption.(But it is perhaps equally surprising that, as we shall soon see, the evidence against the independence of returns over time is as weak as it is.) D. Market Conditions Consistent with Eficiency Before turning to the empirical work, however, a few words about the market conditions that might help or hinder efficient adjustment of prices to information are in order. First, it is easy to determine suficient conditions for capital market efficiency. For example, consider a market in which(i)there are no transactions costs in trading securities, (ii)all available information is costlessly available to all market participants, and (iii)all agree on the im plications of current information for the current price and distributions of future prices of each security. In such a market, the current price of a security bviously" fully refects"all available information But a frictionless market in which all information is freely available and investors agree on its implications is, of course, not descriptive of markets met in practice. Fortunately, these conditions are sufficient for market efficiency, but not necessary. For example, as long as transactors take account of all on the price level. But though rigorous terminology is usually desirable, our loose use of terms should not cause confusion; and our usage follows that of the efficient markets literature in(7)is usually to include only the past return history, r,t r, t-11 5. The random walk model does not say, however, that past information is of no value in essing distributions of future returns. Indeed since return distributions are assumed to be past returns are the best source of such information. The random walk model does say, however, that the sequence(or the order)of the past returns is of no consequence
The Journal of finance available information, even large transactions costs that inhibit the flow of transactions do not in themselves imply that when transactions do take place prices will not "fully reflect "available information. Similarly(and speaking as above, somewhat loosely), the market may be efficient if "sufficient num- bers"of investors have ready access to available information. and disagree ment among investors about the implications of given information does not in itself imply market inefficiency unless there are investors who can consistently make better evaluations of available information than are implicit in market But though transactions costs, information that is not freely available to all investors, and disagreement among investors about the implications of given information are not necessarily sources of market inefficiency, they are poten tial sources. And all three exist to some extent in real world markets. Measur- ing their effects on the process of price formation is, of course, the major goal of empirical work in this area II. THE EVIDENCE All the empirical research on the theory of efficient ts has been con cerned with whether prices fully reflect" particular subsets of available information. Historically, the empirical work evolved more or less as follows The initial studies were concerned with what we call weak form tests in which the information subset of interest is just past price (or return) histories. Most of the results here come from the random walk literature. When extensive tests seemed to support the efficiency hypothesis at this level, attention was turned to semi-strong form tests in which the concern is the speed of price adjustment to other obviously publicly available information (e. g, announcements of stock splits, annual reports, new security issues, etc). Finally, strong form tests in which the concern is whether any investor or groups (e.g, manage- ments of mutual funds) have monopolistic access to any information relevant for the formation of prices have recently appeared. We review the empirical esearch in more or less this historical sequence First, however, we should note that what we have called the efficient markets model in the discussions of earlier sections is the hypothesis that security prices at any point in time"fully reflect"all available information Though we shall argue that the model stands up rather well to the data, it is obviously an extreme null hypothesis, And, like any other extreme null hy posthesis, we do not expect it to be literally true. The categorization of the tests into weak, semi-strong, and strong form will serve the useful purpose of allowing us to pinpoint the level of information at which the hypothesis breaks down. And we shall contend that there is no important evidence against the hypothesis in the weak and semi-strong form tests (i.e prices seem to effi ciently adjust to obviously publicly available information), and only limited evidence against the hypothesis in the strong form tests(i. e, monopolistic access to information about prices does not seem to be a prevalent phenomenon in the investment community)
Eficient Capital Markets 389 1. Random Walks and Fair Games: A Little Historical Background As noted earlier, all of the empirical work on efficient markets can be con- sidered within the context of the general expected return or "fair game del, and much of the evidence bears directly on the special submartingale expected return model of (6). Indeed, in the early literature, discussions of the efficient markets model were phrased in terms of the even more special andom walk model, though we shall argue that most of the early authors were rned with more general versions of the "fair game'model Some of the confusion in the early random walk writings is understandable. Research on security prices did ent of a theory of price formation which was then subjected to empirical tests. Rather, the mpetus for the development of a theory came from the accumulation of ev- idence in the middle 1950s and early 1960 s that the behavior of common stock and other speculative prices could be well approximated by a random walk. Faced with the evidence, economists felt compelled to offer some ratio nalization. What resulted was a theory of efficient markets stated in terms of random walks, but usually implying some more general"fair game ' model It was not until the work of Samuelson [38] and Mandelbrot [27] in 1965 and 1966 that the role of "fair game"expected return models in the theory of efficient markets and the relationships between these models and the theory of random walks were rigorously studied. And these papers came somewhat after the major empirical work on random walks. In the earlier work,"theo- retical""discussions, though usually intuitively appealing, were always lacking in rigor and often either vague or ad hoc. In short, until the Mandelbrot- Samuelson models appeared, there existed a large body of empirical results in search of a rigorous theor Thus, though his contributions were ignored for sixty years, the first state- ment and test of the random walk model was that of Bachelier [3] in 1900 But his "fundamental principle for the behavior of prices was that specula tion should be a"fair game; in particular, the expected profits to the specu- lator should be zero. With the benefit of the modern theory of stochastic processes, we know now that the process implied by this fundamental principle is a martingale. After Bachelier, research on the behavior of security prices lagged until the 6. Basing their analyses on futures contracts in commodity markets, Mandelbrot and Samuelson show that if the price of such a contract at time t is the expected value at t(given information ) of the spot price at the termination of the contract, then the futures price will follow a artingale with respect to the information sequence (p,; that is, the expected price change from riod to period will be zero, and the price changes will be a"fair game. If the equilibrium ex- pected return is not assumed to be zero, our more general"fair game model, summarized by (1) informationΦ, :出= f the assumptions the returns and that the
The journal of finan coming of the computer. In 1953 Kendall [21] examined the behavior of weekly changes in nineteen indices of British industrial share prices and in spot prices for cotton(New York) and wheat( Chicago). After extensive analysis of serial correlations, he suggests, in quite graphic ter The series looks like a wandering one, almost as if once a week the demon of Chance drew a random number from a symetrical population of fixed dispersion and added it to the current price to determine the next weeks price [21, p. 13 Kendall's conclusion had in fact been suggested earlier by Working [47] though his suggestion lacked the force provided by Kendall's empirical results And the implications of the conclusion for stock market research and financial analysis were later underlined by roberts [36 But the suggestion by Kendall, Working, and roberts that series of specula tive prices may be well described by random walks was based on observation None of these authors attempted to provide much economic rationale for the hypothesis, and, indeed, Kendall felt that economists would generally reject it. Osborne [33] suggested market conditions, similar to those assumed by Bachelier, that would lead to a random walk. but in his model, independence of successive price changes derives from the assumption that the decisions of investors in an individual security are independent from transaction to transaction-which is little in the way of an economic model Whenever economists (prior to Mandelbrot and Samuelson) tried to pro vide economic justification for the random walk, their arguments usually ple, Alexander [8, P. 200] states If one were to start out with the assumption that a stock or commodity speculation is a"fair game"with equal expectation of gain or loss or, more accurately, with an expectation of zero gain, one would be well on the way to picturing the behavior of speculative prices as a random walk There is an awareness here that the"fair game "assumption is not sufficient to lead to a random walk, but Alexander never expands on the comment Similarly, Cootner [8, P. 232] states If any substantial group of buyers thought prices were too low, their buying would force up the prices. The reverse would be true for sellers. Except for appreciation due to earnings retention, the conditional expectation of tomorrows price, given today's price, is today's price In such a world, the only price changes that would occur are those that result from new information. Since there is no reason to expect that information to be non-ran movements, statistically independent of one another es of a stock should be random dom nce, the period-to-period price cha Though somewhat imprecise, the last sentence of the first paragraph seems to toa“ fair ga econd paragraph can be viewed as an attempt to describe environmental con- ditions that would reduce a "fai to a random walk. But the tion imposed on the information generating process is insufficier pose; one would, for example, also have to say something 吐or
Eficient Capital markets tastes. Finally, lest I be accused of criticizing others too severely for am- biguity, lack of rigor and incorrect conclusions, By contrast, the stock market trader has a much more practical criterion for judging what constitutes important dependence in successive price changes. For his purposes the random walk model is valid as long as knowledge of the past behavior of the series of price changes cannot be used to increase expected gains. More specif ically, the independence assumption is an adequate description of reality as long the actual degree of dependence in the series of price changes is not sufficient to allow the past history of the series to be used to predict the future in a way which makes expected profits greater than they would be under a naive buy-and hold model [10,p35 We know now, of course, that this last condition hardly requires a random walk. It will in fact be met by the submartingale model of(6) But one should not be too hard on the theoretical efforts of the early em pirical random walk literature. The arguments were usually appealing; where they fell short was in awareness of developments in the theory of stochastic processes. Moreover, we shall now see that most of the empirical evidence in the random walk literature can easily be interpreted as tests of more gene expected return or“ fair game” models 2. Tests of Market Efficiency in the Random Walk Literature as discussed earlier.,“ fair game” models imply the‘ impossibility"of various sorts of trading systems. Some of the random walk literature has been concerned with testing the profitability of such systems. More of the literature has, however, been concerned with tests of serial covariances of returns. We shall now show that. like a random walk the serial covariances of a fair game'are zero, so that these tests are also relevant for the expected return If xt is a"fair game, "its unconditional expectation is zero and its serial covariance can be written in general form as E(t+xf(x ) d where f indicates a density function. But if xt is a"fair game, E(X+1xt)=0 8. Our brief h review is meant only to provide perspective, and it is, of course, somewhat plete. For le, we have ignored the important contributions to the early random walk literature in stu arrant and other options by Sprenkle, kruizenga, Boness, and others. Much of this early work on options is summarized in [8] 9. More generally, if the sequence x, is a fair game with respect to the information sequen (4 ),(i. e, E(x++1l,)=0 for all 4,)i then x, is a fair game with respect to any 't that is a ibset of t (i.e, E(x++1lp' )=0 for all 't ). To show this, let t=('t "t).Then, using Stieltjes integrals and the symbol F to denote cumulative distinction functions, the conditional EG+1=∫x+m(+,1)=「[J广x+m+1)]rs